The crisis of the European Union and the failure of its ‘salvation plans’

The crisis of the European Union and the failure of its ‘salvation plans’

Stavros D. Mavroudeas
Dept. of Economics
University of Macedonia
Greece
https://stavrosmavroudeas.wordpress.com

I. The crisis of European imperialist integration

The year 2011 (and as it seems today quite probable the 2012 also) was marked by the crisis of one of the main international pillars of capitalism: the European Union (EU). What is usually described as a crisis of the Eurozone (strictly speaking the European Monetary Union – EMU) is in fact a crisis of the whole EU edifice system, where EMU is its most avant-gardist structure.

The European integration was one of the most ambitious projects of the 20th century, as Europe’s bourgeoisies tried to form a unified imperialist bloc in the very area of the globe where capitalism was born predominantly in the form of nation-state and where conflicts between national capitalisms took their most brutal forms. In fact, behind the facade of a common European identity, etc. is an imperialist pyramidal structure. On top there are a handful of advanced and strong hegemonic capitalist economies (which have similar structures and are closely linked but never lose their separate national identities). At the intermediate level there are several less robust and less advanced capitalist economies. Finally, the base of the pyramid consists of the countries of the so-called ‘euro-periphery’, i.e. weaker economies. This pyramidal bloc dominates other less developed economies and areas and competes with the other major international poles (most notably the US and the Pacific Basin). But imperialist relations exist also within the European bloc and between its different levels. Imperialist exploitation takes place through the transfer of wealth from weaker to stronger economies.

This project of the European imperialist integration passed through several phases and faced several critical moments (failures of the Common Agricultural Policy and the European Monetary System etc.). Each time it surpassed them through a headlong rush that deepened linkages and the integration process while at the same time ignoring problems and contradictions. It seems that the current economic crisis – that erupted in 2007 – puts an end to this game. It brings to the fore its inherent contradictions in a way that no headlong rush can no longer cope.

II. Understanding the EU crisis

There are two basic mainstream explanations of the current EU crisis. According to the first – derived mainly from EU’s hegemonic top – the European integration has not structural defaults and its problems are basically policy-driven. That is, countries of its lower tier (the PIGS – Portugal, Ireland, Greece and Spain) followed imprudent economic policies by ‘consuming more than they could afford’ (particularly through excessive wage increases); in contrast to their ‘Protestant’ and temperate upper tiers’ ‘partners’. This ‘party’ was supported by fiscal deficits which were financed by external borrowing (facilitated by the low borrowing costs that the euro offered them). By surpassing every limit these imprudent countries were led to extravagant indebtedness which usually took the form of the twin deficits (fiscal deficit and external indebtedness). But PIGS problems threaten to ‘contaminate’ the healthy upper tiers and endanger the whole EU edifice. So their prudent ‘partners’ must come to their rescue through lending schemes but at the same time impose them strict austerity and privatization programs and effectively turning them into economic protectorates for their own sake.

The second mainstream interpretation – stemming largely from the US and England, its closest European ally – recognizes some structural problems in the European integration structure; namely the fact that it is not an optimum currency area. In Marxist terms, this means that the Eurozone is composed of very different economies (i.e. it is riddled by disproportionalities) that have been squeezed into the straitjacket of a single currency (the euro). The latter pertains to some of these economies but not to others. This uneven and dysfunctional structure is prone to problems particularly in times of economic crises that hit differentially its countries-members. To put it simply, economic crises exacerbate the inherent disproportionalities and uneven development levels of the Euroland because they affect dissimilarly its constituent parts. The solution is either the Eurozone evolves into a full economic union (i.e. with fiscal integration and hence wealth transfers from the richest to the poorest in order to balance its disproportionalities) or follows a path of controlled disintegration that does not left it in tatters. The latter because while the U.S. wants to eliminate the threat by the EU against the global hegemony, but do not want an uncontrolled collapse of the EU will create a strategic vacuum in Europe and will likely lead to a reordering of international alliances (e.g. a partnership between the German and Russian bourgeoisies).

Both interpretations are characteristic of the political voluntarism and the apologetic myopia of bourgeois theory. Above all, both interpretations ignore the role of the current economic crisis. Bourgeois theory not only failed utterly to predict the current economic crisis but, once the latter erupted, it hurried to pronounce it as a mere financial crisis. Thus it ignored – similarly to its radical relatives of the financialisation explanation) – the deep roots of the crisis in the very productive structure of capitalism. Put it in a nutshell, bourgeois theory considered the crisis as a chance outcome of wrong actions (primarily financial greed) and not as a structural outcome of the operation-as-usual of the capitalist system. Moreover, it hurried to announce its end by 2011 after the coordinated actions of capitalist states. Of course, today it already fears that this announcement might be proved mere wishful thinking since a ‘double dip’ is nowadays widely expected.

A Marxist interpretation of the current EU crisis should start right from the economic crisis that erupted in 2007-8 (the first great capitalist crisis of the 21st century). The current economic crisis is the consequence of the 1973 structural crisis – which required a radical restructuring of the ‘internal architecture’ of the capitalist system – and the failure of successive waves of capitalist restructuring that followed to create such a new and functional architecture. These capitalist restructuring waves achieved only partially to reverse the declining profit rate and to alleviate the overaccumulation of capital. Especially the last wave, neoliberalism, led to a surge in the internationalization of capital (the so-called ‘globalization’). Once this started faltering it resorted to the extensive use of fictitious capital in conjunction with credit money (the so-called ‘financialization’). This deus-ex-machina managed to postpone the eruption of the crisis but, at the same time, amplified further the problem of capital overaccumulation of capital. As soon as the profitability of productive capital – under the auspices of which surplus-value (and thus total profit) is generated – started tattering crisis re-emerged in all its glory. ‘Financialisation’ gave only a temporary respite to the crisis of profitability but at a very high cost. Namely, it increased significantly the portion of surplus-value extracted by productive capital but accruing to money capital. This aggravated further the falling profitability of productive capital and set the whole house on fire.

For surpassing the crisis capitalist states abandoned hastily their neoliberal credos and resorted massively to state intervention in order to support capitalist profitability. This subsidization of capital accumulation and profit from public funds boosted the usually pre-existing fiscal deficits. Most countries in order to cover these deficits resorted to international borrowing leading to the skyrocketing of external debt. As fears of collapse (the ‘return of the crisis’ and the double dip) increased, this led in the case of several countries to a dramatic increase of borrowing. As a result many countries are flirting with default.

The economic crisis has another crucial repercussion. It aggravates international antagonisms and conflicts, particularly between the major imperialist powers. Each of the major imperialist powers attempts to pass the burden of the crisis on other countries. Here the EU has sought to make a sleigh of hands. With the outbreak of crisis, the U.S. adopted a policy mix characterized by (a) an expansionary fiscal policy and (b) a very loose monetary policy (interest rates to almost zero and successive Quantitative Easing programs). A similar route was adopted by several other economies and, most significantly, China. The latter implemented an expansionary fiscal policy but not a very loose monetary policy (China has no problem of funding since it has plenty of funds). By contrast, the EU has followed a policy mix of (a) a tight fiscal policy and (b) tighter monetary policy (e.g. interest rate cuts were slower and smaller than the FED). This meant that the U.S. and China ‘inflate’ their economies to address the immediate danger of the crisis but also flirt with the perils of a bursting of ‘bubble’ which will rock their international position. On the other hand, the EU seeks to exploit the ‘bubbles’ of its competitors (by selling in their markets) while house-keeping its own economy and of course not providing similar facilities to its competitors. In a telling recent comment (Wall Street Journal, 25/1/2012) Volker Treier, chief economist at Germany’s chambers of commerce declared that Germany’s economy (which accounts for 30% of the eurozone) has benefited from strong growth in emerging markets such as China and a recovering U.S. economy.
Simultaneously, the EU initiated a process of ‘internal chinezation’ by pushing the euro-periphery (particularly the PIGS) into the debt trap. That is, the hegemonic European capitalisms fabricated the explosion of the foreign debt of the PIGS (by manipulating statistics, rumor spreading and calculated attacks). This already led three of them (Greece, Ireland and Portugal) into the straitjackets of the EU-ECB-IMF Memoranda and their austerity programs. Through these Memoranda the euro-peripheral countries are being drawn in a recession spiral accompanied by drastic reductions of wages and rapid deterioration of working relations to the point that they tend towards those of the Chinese economy. In other words, the euro-core is attempting to create its own internal ‘China’. This move does not leave unaffected the bourgeoisies of those euro-periphery countries. They too have to take considerable pain since the Memoranda lead to defaults and falling valuations of enterprises and properties. In a nutshell, these euro-periphery capitalisms are falling back within the international division of labor and are losing their economic sovereignty.

But this EU plan is too cunning to come true. The other major global imperialist poles do not permit the EU to play on their backs. So – especially through the supposedly anonymous ‘markets’ and the rating agencies (two basic tools crucially influenced by the U.S.) – the debt crisis of the euro-periphery was transformed into a debt crisis of the whole EU and as the crisis of the euro. What began as a controlled fire within firewall zones became an uncontrollable fire. Thus, the other global imperialist poles push the EU to ‘inflate’ its economy – both through debt (eurobonds, etc.), but mainly through a European Quantitative Easing policy (especially by printing money). Of course this would put the tombstone on the dreams of a global European imperialist hegemony and will leave the European imperialist pole behind its key competitors. For this reason Germany – having already made in the past (during the SPD-Greens Schroeder administration) its own ‘internal chinezation’ by reducing wage costs and extending flexible labor relations – resists vehemently this prospect.

III. The failure of the successive EU ‘salvation plans’

Once the EU crisis came to the forefront, the European bourgeoisies (headed by the euro-core countries) made several attempts to surpass it. However, all subsequent EU ‘salvation plans’ (including the last one of the December 9th 2011) have been blown apart because of ‘the markets’ distrust of their effectiveness’.

The first batch of plans aimed to show that the EU will not allow any of its members to default. This was based on two axes. The first was that the hegemonic euro-core lends some money to the beleaguered euro-periphery members but with extreme niggardliness. The channels for this are inter-state loans and the creation of an emergency fund, the European Financial Stability Facility – EFSF (inaugurated on May 9th 2010). It is characteristic of their niggardliness the cynical declaration by the German Finance minister Wolfgang Schaeuble that Germany has not actually paid much money into the rescue funds but has given mainly guarantees. The second axis was the acceleration of the process of ‘internal chinezation’ of the euro-periphery. This plan failed very soon as the ‘pressure of the markets’ tested the limits of these salvation mechanisms (and particularly the adequacy of their funds) and as the Memoranda policies led the euro-periphery countries in a steep recessionary spiral that derailed all their projections.

In the next batch of plans the hegemonic euro-core added some more money to the rescue funds. They beefed up a little the EFSF (e.g. agreement of June 24th 2010) and promised the creation of a permanent bailout facility (the European Stability Mechanism – ESM, in October 2010). But the funding for these mechanisms was based mainly on creating certain ‘toxic products’ (in the form of SPIVs with high leverage) that would be sold to China and Russia (and other emerging economies as well). This, of course, was a stupid joke since in times of extreme ‘toxicity’ in the international system none was stupid enough to buy EU’ ‘toxic products’; particularly in times when the EU is at the eye of the debt cyclone. Hence, despite Sarkozy’s humiliating plea to the Chinese, both China and Russia declined to participate .
The recent plan (December 9th 2011) had no better luck and it is already almost dead. This plan envisages a new euro-treaty for deeper fiscal integration with stricter budget rules and more discipline in economic policy for its members. Its main provisions include:

•    a cap of 0.5% of GDP on members’ annual structural deficits
•    automatic penalties for countries whose public deficit exceeds 3% of GDP
•    enshrining these tighter rules in members’ constitutions
•    bringing forward ESM’s introduction (July 2012)
•    reassessing the adequacy of 500bn-euro limit for the ESM
•    EU contributes up to 200bn euros to the IMF to help debt-stricken eurozone members

This new plan, essentially, promises a long term solution to a pressing short-term problem. It offers the ‘cinezation’ of not only the euro-periphery but also of the euro-core countries. This implies a brutal deterioration of the working and living conditions of the working classes in all European countries and, consequently, aggravates social conflicts with unforeseeable outcomes. This is a very long-run solution since it takes considerable time to take place and its very outcome is far from secure. On the other hand, the EU crisis has a much more short-run problem to face: how to solve the sovereign debt problems in its area. This problem requires immediate answers. Moreover, this new plan has several other strategic problems.

First, It implies a further strengthening of the German hegemony (which even France is increasingly hard to tolerate).

Second, the other global imperialist poles know that this will turn against them and are not willing to allow it to proceed unhindered. The opting-out of the United Kingdom is telling. It probably did not happen without the hidden consent of its transatlantic ally (the US). Moreover, it effectively blocked the way for a new EU treaty and led towards the more copious and problematic path of a treaty between governments.


Third, this process of signing a treaty between states is lengthy and fraught with dangers. It requires constitutional coups d’état at both EU and national levels. As the EU crisis deepens – it has already touched not only Italy but also France – it is far from certain whether social and political upheavals will permit its materialization. Already question marks, legal difficulties and politico-economic reservations have started being voiced among its participants.
For all these reasons the ‘Markets Anonymous’ gave already the thumbs down sign to the last plan. In particular, both the US and China are pushing the EU towards the short-term solution of an EU Quantitative Easing. That is why the EU prepares for a new conference and probably another ‘salvation plan’ (at the end of January 2012). But already the ECB is increasingly forced towards a form of mild Quantitative Easing by aggressively buying – or funding the buying – of member-states’ bonds. This is done – at least for the time being – selectively (for example in recent Italian auctions) but with increasing rhythms.

Stavros D. Mavroudeas is an associate professor in the Department of Economics, University of Macedonia, Greece. 

 

Published in the following sites:

SPECTREZINE

http://www.spectrezine.org/crisis-european-union-and-failure-its-%E2%80%98salvation-plans%E2%80%99

BRECHT FORUM

http://brechtforum.org/economywatch/eu-best-laid-plans

1 responses to “The crisis of the European Union and the failure of its ‘salvation plans’

  1. Παράθεμα: Απλά Μαθήματα Οικονομίας: 2ο μέρος συνέντευξης στον ΕΡΓΑΤΙΚΟ ΑΓΩΝΑ « Stavros Mavroudeas Blog

Σχολιάστε

Ο ιστότοπος χρησιμοποιεί το Akismet για την εξάλειψη των ανεπιθύμητων σχολίων. Μάθετε πως επεξεργάζονται τα δεδομένα των σχολίων σας.